September 13, 2010
Poison Pill Forum: Steven Davidoff
Posted by Erik Gerding

Steven Davidoff (Connecticut) has some incisive analysis of eBay v. Newmark on his Deal Professor column on the New York Times' Dealbook site. 

He ends the column by engaging our own Conglomerate forum topic on poison pills.  He starts with a comment that eBay isn't all that interesting as a poison pill case.  To follow Christine's analysis (and to borrow from craigslist lingo), perhaps we should flag Chancellor Chandler's posting as "miscategorized" -- is the case really about takeovers or about minority shareholder oppression or disenfranchisement?

Steven then gives a nice summary of what two cases that clearly do change poison pill jurisprudence -- Selectica and the Vice Chancellor Strine's opinion in the Barnes & Noble litigation -- mean for the looming legal battle over Air Product's takeover attempt on Airgas. 

Permalink | Corporate Governance| Corporate Law| Delaware| eBay| Forum: Poison Pills| M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

August 09, 2010
Notice to Law Students: Get ready for the coming M&A boom
Posted by Gordon Smith

While I was teaching in London this past month, I told my students -- most of whom had just finished their first year of law school -- that their job prospects would brighten substantially over the next two years, led by a boom in mergers and acquisitions. My prediction was accompanied by the usual disclaimers: the views expressed here are entirely impressionistic and not based on systematic study or expertise. Nevertheless, the stars seem to be aligning. Banks are strengthening their balance sheets and becoming profitable. The weak economy has exposed vulnerable companies, but it has helped many other companies to become leaner. Consider the following from today's FT

In a buoyant second-quarter results season, two-thirds of European groups beat analyst forecasts; predictions suggest that leading American companies will report record profits this year. Businesses are flush with cash as they reap the benefits of rigorous cost-cutting and borrowing rates at historic lows. 

Even the most bullish executives privately acknowledge that there are risks to the recovery as some of the reasons underlying it evaporate and concerns persist over how developed countries tackle their public debt. But for now many of them are basking in a remarkable corporate renaissance in which size is a factor. “The strong are getting stronger and the weak are getting weaker. The competitive advantage has gone to the bigger companies,” says the chief executive of one group with $100bn revenues.

With the exception of Europe, global merger activity has already picked up this year. And John Carney's latest at CNBC suggests that at least some lawyers on getting ready:

The move of the Hanrahan team from midtown’s Lipstick building to One Chase Manhattan Plaza, in the heart of the financial district, shows that New York law firms are prepping for a big comeback for M&A debt financing. It seems likely that the clients of these lawyers—big financial institutions—are letting them know that lending standards may once again be easing and credit becoming more available for leveraged finance driven deals.

As John observes, we are projecting based on anecdote, and the risks are still grave, but there seems to be some cause for optimism.

UPDATE: Larry Ribsten posted on John's story over at Truth on the Market, asking "Would a big increase in m & a activity mean a rebirth of Big Law?" Larry notes that this is area of legal practice in which Big Law is thought to have big advantages, but he is still wondering about the effect of outsourcing and technology. It's worth reading his Death of Big Law to see the argument in full.

Permalink | Financial Crisis| M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

June 03, 2010
The Future of Newsweek
Posted by Christine Hurt

Newsweek is on the block.  The Washington Post Co. is accepting nonbinding bids for the 77 year-old magazine, and a few prospective buyers are lining up.  However, most name brands have declined:  Bloomberg, Thomson-Reuters, U.S. News & World Report.

I used to love Newsweek.  It was my airport purchase of choice.  I never had a subscription though, because it was so expensive.  I remember getting a call form a marketer once who would give me three other subscriptions for free (I think my picks were Oprah, Vanity Fair and something else) for purchasing a Newsweek subscription.  When I was in practice, I received an offer a week to purchase a subscription for "half off the newstand price," but it was still expensive.  Weekly magazines subscriptions are expensive. 

But now I rarely buy it, even in the airport.  If the morning newspaper seems to have stories that are already familiar, then reading a weekly magazine seems a lot like reading a 6 day-old newspaper.  And Newsweek's concept was news.  Mostly short pieces similar to a newspaper article or a blog post, with a few longer pieces, with more texture and interviews.  So, these days, you're paying $4 for the two long pieces, a lot of articles you've already read, and the cartoon/quotations page.  The weekly format just got squeezed by the Internet.  Weekly deadlines make sure that almost everything is stale and nothing is incredibly deep and thoughtful.  I actually love the articles in Vanity Fair, which are often about the financial industry, well-written and in-depth.  But I'm sure they take more than 4 days to write.

But what about People magazine?  It's a weekly, it's expensive, and it's very popular.  But what is in there isn't available on the Internet.  They have exclusive photographs.  Good ones, that I'm sure they pay for.  They also have exclusive interviews with celebrities, which they may also pay for.  Yes, you see on the Internet that Sandra Bullock is separated from her husband, but People magazine has the exclusive interview.  Two other things that sets People magazine out from the crowd.  First, it's more reliable than their competition.  If you look at a grocery store checkout aisle, four other magazines will have a cover that says that Hollywood couple No. 347 is divorcing because of (1) strange religious practice; (2) same-sex affair; (3) opposite-sex affair; (4) plastic surgery; (5) baby or lack thereof; or (6) aliens.  The cover of People magazine will be silent on the topic.  I don't believe any celebrity gossip unless it's in People magazine.  Second, People magazine may sell to a different demographic than the one that is following every celebrity on Twitter and scanning the internet constantly for news.  So, what's in People is still news to the mom at the grocery store who gets to check Facebook every other day, and People is amazingly good at getting things in the weekly magazine that seemed to have happened six hours ago.  The same people who would buy Newsweek have already kept up with most of the news that's in the latest issue.

So, stay tuned to see who wins the auction and what they will do with Newsweek once they win.

Permalink | Internet| M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

April 07, 2010
United/US Air Part Deux
Posted by Erik Gerding

The NY Times is reporting that United and US Air are in merger talks.

Ten years ago, the last time these two airlines were courting each other, I lived in D.C., and it was that market that caused the most antitrust concerns.  United has a hub at Dulles, while US Air has one in Philadelphia and has major operations out of National.

Will this courtship turn out differently?  Are the continuing struggles of the airlines enough to overcome union and antitrust obstacles?  (Don't ask me.  I won't even pretend to be an antitrust scholar.)

Which of the potentially eight hubs of the combined airline (SF, LAX, Phoenix, Denver, O'Hare, Philly, Dulles, Charlotte) would be downgraded?  Living in the Southwest, I hope it would be none of the western ones.  Phoenix might seem like a good candidate, although the city has stealthily grown into one of the five largest in the country.  I am also rooting for Philly to remain viable.  The US Air hub there keeps prices down when we fly back to God's Country (aka New Jersey).

Permalink | Alliances| Antitrust| M&A| Travel | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

March 12, 2010
What Do Investment Bankers Do?
Posted by David Zaring

During the financial crisis, the last administration, staffed by investment bankers, tried to furiously deal its way out of the mess.  TED has a post up that suggests that perhaps we should not be surprised, given the business model, and ultimately the culture, of investment banking:

a senior banker in a revenue generating role at a large investment bank is often expected to deliver $25 million or more in transaction-related revenues to the bank each and every year. Below that, senior management just doesn't think he's producing enough. (Among other things, there's a hell of a lot of infrastructure to pay for in a big bank.) But you can't do that unless you are doing deals: mergers and acquisitions, stock and bond underwritings, derivatives. Do you see the problem? It just doesn't pay to offer good advice. A banker could and should be doing deals instead.

Permalink | M&A | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

January 02, 2010
The Newest Tile in My Mosaic - Private Equity and the Heightened Fiduciary Duty of Disclosure
Posted by Trey Drury

My most recent article, Private Equity and the Heightened Fiduciary Duty of Disclosure, is coming out in the latest volume of NYU's Journal of Law & Business. 

There, I argue that Delaware courts are concerned with conflicts of interest in private equity deals and are subjecting them to more intense scrutiny than strategic transactions.  As a result of this scrutiny, several private equity deals have been enjoined, while strategic deals with similar defects have not.

The interesting thing, at least to me, is how Delaware is doing it.  Instead of enjoining transactions on loyalty grounds, which would be deadly to those deals, courts are finding disclosure deficiencies.  Using this approach, Delaware tries to have its cake and eat it too.  It voices its disapproval of the process and ultimately allows shareholders to decide if they want the fruits of the tainted search.

Check it out and let me know what you think.

Permalink | Delaware| Legal Scholarship| M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

December 22, 2009
Legal Advice M&A League Tables
Posted by David Zaring

It is that time of year, and via Above The Law, here's the M&A league tables for the first three quarters of 2009.  Congratulations to Skadden, and it looks like Davis Polk is coming back after a terrible 2008.

Permalink | M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

September 27, 2009
Until We Meet Again
Posted by Afra Afsharipour

Before signing off, I want to thank The Conglomerate for allowing me to use this forum to share some of my ideas with all of you.  I would also like to thank the terrific readers who have reached out to me these past few weeks with some very insightful comments.  I am impressed by the wide readership of The Conglomerate which includes scholars, practitioners and students.  Earlier in my posts I asked whether "to blog or not to blog" and, thanks to the input from David, Usha, and some Glom readers, I look forward to blogging again in the near future.  I am beginning to be convinced that (to borrow from Edward R. Murrow) “This instrument can teach, it can illuminate; yes, and even it can inspire, but it can do so only to the extent that humans are determined to use it to those ends.”  So I hope The Conglomerate crew continues with the great work that keeps those like me inspired followers.

As for me, I hope to continue my research on reverse termination fee (RTF) provisions.  In one of my earlier posts I talked about the increasing use of RTF provisions to provide greater contractual flexibility and greater creativity in allocating deal risks.  I also spoke about some of the lingering problems of the RTF structure, including the process by which the actual amount of the fee was set and the lack of clear disclosure to shareholders about the risks faced by both the buyer and the seller when agreeing to contracts with RTF structures.  Some of these problems have much to offer for judicial review of board decision-making and public company disclosure – topics that I will explore in a companion paper that I hope to post on SSRN in the coming months.  Of course I welcome your thoughts on these topics.

Permalink | Administrative| M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

September 22, 2009
The law & practice of cross-border M&A
Posted by Afra Afsharipour

Other than spending time studying reverse termination fees, I’ve been spending the past year thinking about and researching the role of law and legal culture in cross-border M&A transactions.  When I was in practice, cross-border deals were even more complicated and more engaging than domestic M&A deals.  Who doesn’t enjoy conference calls at 3 am with Israeli counsel trying to explain arcane Israeli tax issues, the miscommunication regarding regulatory review that undoubtedly occurs with British counsel, trying the explain Delaware’s standards of heightened scrutiny to Indian counsel, etc. 

According to the Deal Professor, “a driver of future deal growth will probably come from cross-border and intraregional takeovers.”  I think that is a good thing not just for deal lawyers but for transactional law scholars.  Suffice it to say, there is not an abundance of comparative corporate law scholarship by US legal scholars that examines the laws affecting cross-border M&A deals and the “law of the deal” produced by parties in cross-border acquisitions.  This is especially true with respect to scholarship that studies laws in developing countries and deals where one of the parties is located in or from a developing country.  John Armour and David Skeel have done important work in studying the divergence in US and UK takeover legislation (see here for their law review piece and here for their shorter summary), I’d love to see this kind of work extended.  Currently I am focusing on the role of law and legal culture in outbound M&A activity by Indian multinationals and the differences in deal-making by these emerging economy buyers.  If you are working on scholarly projects that involve cross-border deals, I would love to hear from you.

Permalink | Comparative Law| M&A| Transactional Law | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

September 14, 2009
Strategic Deals and Reverse Termination Fees
Posted by Afra Afsharipour

I first want to thank Gordon Smith and company for the invitation to guest blog on The Conglomerate.  I have been a devoted follower of this blog going back to my days as a transactional lawyer.  In fact, Gordon and crew helped to inspire me to enter academia, and I learned a lot from their blog, as well as from other faculty blogs, about how to transition from practice to this fabulous new life.  After seven years as a corporate lawyer, I began teaching at UC Davis School of Law in 2007.

   

I am pretty passionate about corporate law, especially comparative corporate law, transactional law and deal-making.  During my visit, I hope to explore some of these issues, as well as share some thoughts on incorporating transactional law and skills in the classroom.   

 

My current obsession (and my poor family really does see this as an obsession) is with reverse termination fees (RTFs) as a risk allocation tool in merger agreements. While standard termination fees, i.e. fees payable by the seller to the buyer, have been analyzed for years by both practitioners and scholars, RTFs have received minimal attention.  I think that it is time that both scholars and practitioners think more deeply about these and other similar provisions (like ticking fees), their current uses and their potential for deal innovation. It is clear that there are some others who are also thinking about these issues (HT: M&A Law Prof blog).

 

For the past couple of years there have been anecdotal reports of an increasing use of RTFs in strategic deals.  My current paper confirms these reports through a study of strategic acquisition agreements involving US public companies during two separate periods, January 1, 2003 through December 31, 2004 and January 1, 2008 through June 30, 2009.  An analysis of each of these agreements demonstrates that in the 2003-04 period parties predominantly used RTF provisions to allocate similar risks to those allocated by STFs, such as the risk that the buyer would terminate the agreement due to a superior proposal for the buyer.  Thus, it was unsurprising that in a substantial majority of the reviewed agreements, the RTF was equal to the STF.  The findings were quite different for the 2008-09 period.  Not only has there been a significant increase in the use of RTFs, as compared to the 2003-04 period, but the data also shows that while in some transactions RTFs continue to be set at an equal amount to STFs, parties have also become more creative by using hybrid and liability cap approaches.  This more creative approach to RTFs reflects the use of the provisions to allocate deal risk beyond just the risk of non-consummation due to a competing offer for the buyer, such as financing risk or the risk of a breach of contract by the buyerFurthermore, in a sizeable number of the 2008-09 transactions that I studied, parties had altogether abandoned specific performance as a contractual remedy and specified that the RTF was the seller's sole remedy in the event the deal failed to close for any reason.

 

Overall, the study demonstrates that the shift in contractual triggers that give rise to RTFs provides buyers greater flexibility to walk away from transactions.  In future posts I will talk about some theories as to why this shift has occurred and the implications it may have on the ways in which we view merger agreements and review board decision-making.  Suffice it to say, I think that my obsession with RTFs has led me to think and write even more about these issues.

Permalink | Contracts| M&A| Transactional Law | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

September 09, 2009
Kraft & Cadbury: Is it All About the Gum?
Posted by Christine Hurt

So, in a time that is a little light on interesting mergers and acquisitions, here's a story we can chew on for awhile.  (Ha, ha.)  Kraft has made a bid for Cadbury, at a price with a substantial premium (31% over share price), only to be told that it is way too low.  Well, there goes that whole efficient market thing.  Cadbury is in the middle of a strategic plan to increase profitability and share price, and here comes Kraft trying to buy into that momentum.  WSJ story here; NYT story here.  Cadbury is known in Europe for chocolate, but it also has gum.  Kraft doesn't have gum.  In recessions, people eat gum.  Hmmm.

Stay tuned.  Hershey, which already has a distribution deal with Cadbury, may jump in.

Permalink | M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

April 06, 2009
I.B.M. Withdraws Offer to Acquire Sun Microsystems
Posted by Christine Hurt

I'm rushing off to class, but I wanted to note quickly that I.B.M. has broken off negotiations with Sun over the weekend.  But lawyers take heart:  I.B.M.'s change in tone came after 100 lawyers engaged in extensive due diligence.  So, there is a second-year associate somewhere who can't believe the coolest deal she's gotten to work on so far just died over the weekend, but at least her hours for March were good.

Permalink | M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

April 03, 2009
IBM and Sun
Posted by Christine Hurt

With so few fun deals to talk about these days, we have to enjoy the ones we have.  The IBM acquisition of Sun Microsystems seems to be coming to fruition at $9.55 a share ($7B), representing an almost 100% premium over the pre-announcement (or pre-rumor) price. (WSJ story here.) In fact, Sun recently lowered it's original asking price to make sure it kept I.B.M. in the game.  The new agreement has a lower price but a pretty strong termination penalty, according to reports. 

Remember that Sun shares were $250 in 2000, when Sun touted that it was the "dot in 'dot.com'" and this acquisition takes on a lot more narrative than it had before.  Here is the old guard,  I.B.M., snagging up Sun, one of the hottest hardware companies in the 1990s.  Everything old is new again.

For nostalgia's sake, here is a 10-year retrospective on Sun's share price, as compared to the NASDAQ composite index:

SUNjpeg

Permalink | M&A | Comments (0) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

October 23, 2008
The Mythology of Value Creation: Lawyers, Neckties, and Balinese Cock-Fighting
Posted by Jeff Lipshaw

Usha's post below, with its reference to Ronald Gilson's 1984 article on value creation by lawyers, prompts me to a short rant, not about Usha's post, but about the article, which Usha rightly calls a "classic" and  "the reigning academic account of what business lawyers actually do."  Honestly, with all due respect to Professor Gilson (who joined the Stanford faculty the year I left as a student), the article has bugged me since I read it a couple years ago; indeed, I have a comprehensive list from a Lexis search I did a while back of every article that had cited it, because I was trying to do a literature search to see if anybody else had said what I'm about to say here.  Since I haven't followed up on my list, I don't know, and I therefore apologize if I'm repeating a critique somebody has already written.  I also apologize for the stream of consciousness approach that follows.

What about the article bugs me?  Let me count the ways:

1.  If I were taken with law and economics in 1984, but had no way of showing empirically that the reams and reams of hours that lawyers spent doing deals actually produced anything with intrinsic value (which Professor Gilson forthrightly admitted, at pp. 247-48 of the article), but was inclined to hope that they did, with an interest in justifying their existence (as again Professor Gilson forthrightly admitted at footnote 149), this is, I suppose, exactly the article I would write.  What we have here is an attempt to make sense of the world, by way of scientific (or quasi-scientific) theory, but it is "over-determined" in the sense that the theory selected happens to be rational actor economics, rather than, say, the theoretical view Clifford Geertz applied to Balinese cock-fighting.

2.  The theory is capsuled as follows.  All transactions occur because buyers value an asset more than sellers.  The difference between the two values is surplus.  Haggling over the split of the surplus is of no interest generally to economists; that is mere strategic bargaining.  Each party, being rational, would know that hiring a lawyer to grab a bigger portion of the surplus won't work, because the other side will respond in kind, and the lawyers, not the parties, would get the benefit of the surplus.  So, in the long run, rational actors being what they are, it must be the case that "[t]he increase must be in the overall value of the transaction, not merely in the distributive share of one of the parties. That is, a business lawyer must show the potential to enlarge the entire pie, not just to increase the size of one piece at the expense."  That's a rational actor trope, and one that I have criticized in another context here.

3.  As I said in a comment to Usha's post, if I were to apply an economic model to lawyers in deals it would be the Prisoner's Dilemma. Both clients would be better off cooperating by throwing all the lawyers out of the room for most of the issues in the deal, hence eliminating the transaction cost of arguing over myriad reps and warranties and other contract niceties that don't make any difference anyway. So imagine a Prisoner's Dilemma matrix with Party A and Party B, and the choice for each is "Lawyer" or "No Lawyer." The payoff for each side choosing "No Lawyer" is a huge reduction in costs (say, 5, 5) compared to both sides choosing "Lawyer" (say, 10, 10)" But both sides keep their lawyers, for fear of the (1, 20) or (20, 1) outcomes in the Lawyer/No Lawyer boxes that are akin to one prisoner confessing but the other one not.

4.  There are places where lawyers reduce transaction costs, say, by mediating between two positions to reach a solution, but there's nothing particularly lawyerly about that. That's a negotiating skill.  Moreover, lawyers may well be necessary to getting the deal through the regulatory thicket, whether it is Hart-Scott-Rodino pre-merger notification or CFIUS review.  But that hardly seems fair, because lawyers created the regulatory thicket.

5.  We have a neighborhood association in northern Michigan.  A lot of people in the association are rich.  When something happens that they don't like, they say things like, "if you do that, I'll have 10 lawyers from the Humungous Law Firm, who I have on retainer, up here the next day."  Since I'm a lawyer, and I used to be a partner at the Humungous Law Firm, I laugh at that, but it's an effective club when wielded against non-lawyers.  I rarely hear non-rich people say this, which goes to my next point.

6.  Professor Gilson's "empirical" testing of this theory is to walk through the most heavily lawyered of all documents, the typical business acquisition agreement.  If lawyers really created value accordingly to the theory, we ought to be able to test it not in mega-million or mega-billion dollar deals, but in little deals that happen all the time.  But the reality there is that most transactions occur without lawyers.  Sometimes there is boilerplate that lawyers had a hand in.  But if a lawyer being involved in a transaction necessarily made the pie bigger, why don't lawyers appear in almost all transactions?

7.  Professor Gilson spends many pages on the information-exchanging value of representations and warranties, and puzzles over the lack of any indemnification mechanism in public company deals (the representations and warranties expire at closing largely because once the proceeds in stock or cash are distributed to widely dispersed shareholders, there's no putting Humpty-Dumpty back together again). He acknowledges that indemnification may be partial or limited in time (there's also the "basket" or deductible, but I don't think that gets mentioned), but the real question, it seems to me, is whether the actual instances of acting on the indemnification clauses warrant the investment in the reps and warranties.  My guess is they have some amount of in terrorem effect, but neither of us have a whole lot of data to go on.  (The one empirical study of which I'm aware on this subject is by Steve Schwarcz, and it is based on surveys of clients who hire transactional lawyers.  To quote Steve's abstract:  "Contrary to existing scholarship, which is based mostly on theory, this article shows that transactional lawyers add value primarily by reducing regulatory costs, thereby challenging the reigning models of transactional lawyers as 'transaction cost engineers' and 'reputational intermediaries.'")

8.  My equally non-testable theory is that lawyers sometimes add value to deals, sometimes subtract value, and appear most of the time during the deal for the same reason neckties do:  it's part of the ritual.  There is no intrinsic reason they have to be there.  Lawyers, like neckties, have value, not because they necessarily make the pie bigger, any more than neckties make the pies bigger, but because somebody values the lawyer enough to pay more for her to be there than it cost for her to get there (marginally speaking, of course).  That's the reason we buy $75 neckties and Rolex watches as well.  But we don't feel a need to justify the presence of the necktie or the watch as a "transaction cost mechanism."

9.  I am persuaded by years of observation that great lawyers (like Jim Freund, who Professor Gilson cites repeatedly) help make deals, but that there is nothing particularly lawyerly about it.  It is, as Vic Fleischer suggests, quarterbacking, or as David Zaring suggests, closing.  That strikes me as an aspect of leadership, something business schools teach, but with which law schools and law (qua law) struggle immensely. 

10.  Mostly, though, I step back and see the process as something akin to a Balinese cockfight, a ritual or ceremony that gives us some limited assurance of certainty in a highly uncertain and contingent world.  I find it equally plausible that the presence of all those lawyers doesn't do a damned thing to make the pie bigger - but they are necessary, and they do have value, just as the accoutrements to the cock-fight have value to the participants.  Their value is in what they do to give us the courage to overcome fear, panic, seller's remorse, buyer's remorse, and risk averseness. Again, as I said over in the comments, lawyers provide an alternative model for resolving disputes about the deal that is better than pistols at twenty paces, but the idea that the contract language provides certainty in anything other than trivial cases is a self-justifying illusion for lawyers.  I suppose what really bugs me comes from my intuition that the Gilson thesis is theory-laden in the sense that Ian Shapiro criticized in The Flight from Reality in the Human Sciences.  What comes first is the economic model and its assumptions about value and rationality, which is then imposed on a linguistic exercise, which is itself an imperfect model of a complex world.

Permalink | Law & Economics| Legal Theory| M&A| Rants | Comments (11) | TrackBack (1) | Bookmark

October 21, 2008
Huntsman, Apollo, and Contract Theory
Posted by Jeff Lipshaw

I have decided to take a break from my two current obsessive-compulsive tics:  minute-by-minute visits to fivethirtyeight.com and to the Dow ticker.

Others have commented on the dispute between Huntsman and Apollo over the "material adverse change" clause (or "MAC").  In a nutshell, Apollo, a private equity group, had purchased four chemical companies, merging them into a group called Hexion.  After a extended bidding contest involving Basell, Hexion (controlled by Apollo) executed an agreement to purchase Huntsman at $28 per share.  During the post-signing due diligence, however, Apollo's financial advisers came to the conclusion that the addition of Huntsman debt to Hexion would render the latter insolvent, triggering what I think is referred to as a "non-payment default" in Hexion's banking agreements.  Apollo invoked the MAC, and sued in Delaware asking the court for a declaration that it was entitled to walk away.  As Steve Davidoff reported, Vice-Chancellor Lamb ruled in an 89-page opinion that there had been no MAC and ordered Hexion to show up at the closing.

I've had sitting on my desk for over a month now the front page Wall Street Journal story on the dispute.  It preceded Vice-Chancellor Lamb's ruling, but it wasn't the technical contract dispute that got me interested.  It was this from Jon Huntsman in reaction to a "down-bid" from $25 to $24 per share in the pre-contract negotiations. "We deal throughout the world with people whose word means something. . . But with these firms, it's hard to know today what tomorrow's price will be."  Even after the deal was signed, Huntsman had Apollo's two senior executives to his Deer Valley mansion, along with the Huntsman board, a number of Huntsman's friend, and Utah's two senators, Orrin Hatch and Robert Bennett.  According to the Journal:  "Mr. Huntsman says he was suspicious of Apollo's willingness to close the deal at that point. 'It was important to me that I have Black and Harris [the Apollo execs] shake hands with them at our Deer Valley home. . .I wanted them to look [the senators] in the eye and tell them it was a done deal.'"  (Disclaimer:  it is public knowledge that, in his role as ecclesiastical leader, Jon Huntsman interviewed Gordon Smith in 1985 in connection with Gordon's impending marriage.  It's not clear from the record whether Mr. Huntsman had the power to put the kibosh on the proposed union, but we do have that bit of data on his good judgment or lack thereof.)

For contract theorists, this is a tough piece of data to assimilate, particularly if one is trying to come up with a universal justification for the involvement of the state in enforcing private agreements, presumably with close questions of doctrine hanging in the balance between the two views:  is the policy based on a moral imperative about promise-keeping, or is it based on economic efficiency and welfare enhancement?  As Ethan Leib observed, the theoreticians seem to be ships passing in the night, but for reasons that I find ironic.  Over in the Yale Law Journal, Daniel Markovits' Kantian "respect for persons" justification expressly disclaimed application to business entities, and the Schwartz & Scott economic justification of contract formalism expressly only applied to business entities of a certain size.  Over at the Harvard Law Review, in her critique of the immorality (or amorality) of aspects of contract doctrine like efficient breach, Seana Shiffrin admits she doesn't know how corporate officers deal with efficient breach, and, anyway, she may be affected by her "overly blunt anticorporatism."

Indeed, part of the Schwartz & Scott logic supporting contract formalism is that corporate executives go to business school and learn how to make optimizing rather than cognitively erroneous decisions, and to perform complex game-theoretic reasoning (if you don't believe me, see 113 Yale L.J. at 551, n. 17; my complete critique of this article is here at the text accompanying footnotes 101-122). So where does that leave Jon Huntsman in all of this, regardless of his lawyers' success in persuading Vice-Chancellor Lamb that the contract's formal provisions were congruent with the immanent morality of the situation as evidenced not by contract but by given word, handshake, and look-in-the-eye? 

Well, that's merely money.  More importantly, where does it leave the contract theorists?  Forever flummoxed, I think, if they try to create models that fail to recognize we are all moral agents, and all economic opportunists, and all at the same time.  My attempt at the final, unimpeachable, most universal, satisfy everybody but satisfy nobody reconciliation of it all is here.

Now back to the financial crisis.

Permalink | Contracts| M&A | Comments (1) | TrackBack (0) | Bookmark

Bloggers
Papers
Posts
Recent Comments
Popular Threads
Search The Glom
The Glom on Twitter
Archives by Topic
Archives by Date
September 2014
Sun Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri Sat
  1 2 3 4 5 6
7 8 9 10 11 12 13
14 15 16 17 18 19 20
21 22 23 24 25 26 27
28 29 30        
Miscellaneous Links